首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
相似文献
 共查询到20条相似文献,搜索用时 31 毫秒
1.
基于零售商线上线下销售与消费者退货并存的双渠道供应链,构建考虑退货的双渠道供应链定价模型以及考虑跨渠道退货策略的双渠道供应链定价决策模型。通过理论分析和数值实验对比,研究集中决策与分散决策下的零售商最优定价策略以及总利润的变化情况,同时分析在不同退货策略下顾客偏好以及退货率对零售商定价和收益的影响。结果表明:零售商渠道的最优价格设置与顾客对渠道的偏好成正比,与退货率成正比。当顾客对某一渠道偏好程度高时,分散决策下的利润要高于集中决策,并且随着该渠道退货率的提高,这种利润差距会进一步扩大,因此零售商应实施分散决策的渠道策略,鼓励线上线下两个渠道进行竞争,从而获得更大的收益。从仿真结果可以看出,对于一般的服装产品,提供跨渠道退货服务的零售商总利润更高,在一定条件下跨渠道服务水平的投入会增加零售商的收入,但这种投入应该控制在一个合理的水平上,并保持服务与顾客回报之间的正相关关系。  相似文献   

2.
本文以全渠道零售商不同渠道的定价为背景,以企业利润最大化为目标,以顾客退货给零售商带来的损失为出发点,从三种不同的退货方式分析退货损失对零售商不同渠道最优定价和利润的影响。首先分析传统的原渠道退货(即:从购买产品的渠道退货),然后分析所有顾客都通过线上渠道退货,进而分析所有顾客都通过线下渠道退货。研究表明:三种退货方式下,当零售商与顾客的线上单位产品净退货损失之和小于线下单位产品净退货损失之和时,全渠道零售商选择全部退货到线上渠道可获得最大利润;当零售商与顾客的线上单位产品净退货损失之和大于线下单位产品净退货损失之和时,全渠道零售商应选择全部退货到线下的退货方式以获得最大利润;传统的退货方式不会让零售商获得最大利润。本文研究对于全渠道零售虑顾客退货损失的基础上,设置最合理的退货方式和不同渠道之间的最优定价有一定的指导意义和实际应用价值。  相似文献   

3.
在电子商务环境下,宽松的退货政策能够刺激需求,促进货品销量的增长,但与此同时也导致了退货量的增多。在面临高退货,特别是无缺陷退货不断攀升的挑战下,在线商家应如何制定合理的退货策略成为值得研究的一个问题。本文主要针对退货运费承担问题,重点比较消费者承担退货运费、商家承担退货运费、双方共同承担退货运费三种策略,探讨不同策略下在线零售商的最优定价及其盈利能力。研究结果表明:为实现利润最大化,在线零售商应根据商品的无缺陷退货比例特征选择相应的策略。具体而言,当商品的无缺陷退货比例较低时,宜采用消费者承担退货运费策略;当无缺陷退货比例高时,宜采用商家承担退货运费策略;当无缺陷退货比例居中时,宜采用共同承担退货运费策略。值得注意的是,退货政策的目的是为了刺激需求的增长,但有时退货政策对需求的促进作用不够理想,不能抵消退货的负面影响,那么这种情况下则无论无缺陷退货占比如何,在线零售商的最佳退货策略只能是让消费者承担退货运费,以此避免更多非理性退货行为的发生。  相似文献   

4.
针对由制造商和在线零售商组成的供应链系统,在存在消费者退货情形下,考虑在线零售商在线上渠道提供促销与退款保证服务,其中在线零售商促销成本为其私有信息,建立了信息不对称下的供应链博弈模型,研究了在线零售商的最优促销策略与供应链合同设计问题;进而分析了不对称信息对供应链均衡的影响,考察了退款保证对供应双方期望利润、信息价值以及消费者剩余的影响。研究发现,当制造商在决策合同参数(设计合同)时,需要在在线零售商信息租金与供应链系统绩效损失之间进行权衡;若满足一定条件,制造商和在线零售商之间进行谈判并能够实现信息共享而分享整个系统的利润;当退货产品总是会给供应链成员造成损失时,退款保证会导致制造商和零售商期望利润的损失,但在一定条件下却能提升消费者剩余。  相似文献   

5.
针对由制造商和线上零售商组成的供应链,考虑消费者退货行为以及产品退货会给企业造成退货损失,且线上零售商退货损失为其私有信息,研究不对称信息下的供应链定价、O2O渠道策略以及合同设计问题,分析线上零售商引入O2O渠道的可行条件及其对供应双方最优决策和消费者剩余的影响,考察不对称信息对各个企业、供应链系统利润的影响。研究表明,线上零售商引入O2O渠道存在可行条件,取决于退货损失的大小;当线上零售商引入O2O渠道时,制造商和供应链系统的期望利润水平均能得到有效提升;O2O渠道策略有利于提高消费者剩余,但到体验店体验产品的消费者不一定能够得到更高的消费者剩余;如果满足一定条件,则线上零售商会选择信息共享谈判与制造商共享其私有信息,进而实现"双赢"。  相似文献   

6.
Retailers selling products with valuation uncertainty often offer return policies to consumers to stimulate demand. However, some products that do not meet consumers’ expectations cannot be returned to the retailers either because of retailers’ strict restrictions on returns or because of short trial period. With the development of e-commerce, consumers who cannot return their products to retailers can resell them directly to others through electronic peer-to-peer (P2P) second-hand goods markets. This paper examines the effect of the presence of a P2P market on a retailer’s optimal return policy when the consumers are strategic and uncertain about their valuations. As a benchmark, we first examine the retailer’s optimal return policy when there is only a retailer-run resale market. Then, we analyze the retailer’s optimal return policy in presence of both the retailer-run resale market and the P2P market. Theoretical and numerical results show that, first, the presence of the P2P market is detrimental to the retailer in most cases. The presence of the P2P market is beneficial to the retailer only when the unit purchasing cost is very high, the consumers’ acceptance of products in the P2P market is relatively high and the transaction cost in the P2P market is relatively low; second, the consumer surplus is improved by the presence of P2P market; third, when the retailer-run resale market is the only second-hand products market, returned products are sold out; while in presence of the P2P market, the retailer will hold some inventory when the unit purchasing cost is very low; fourth, the selling price of new products is increased and the selling price of second-hand products in the retailer-run resale market is decreased with the emergence of the P2P market while the refund amount is increased in most cases.  相似文献   

7.
To understand whether retailers should consider consumer returns when merchandising, we study how the optimal assortment of a retailer is influenced by its return policy. The retailer selects its assortment from an exogenous set of horizontally differentiated products. Consumers make purchase and keep/return decisions in nested multinomial logit fashion. Our main finding is that the optimal assortment has a distinct structure for relatively strict return policies: it is optimal to offer a mix of the most popular and most eccentric products when the refund amount is sufficiently low, which can be viewed as a form of risk sharing between the retailer and consumers. In contrast, if the refund is sufficiently high or when returns are disallowed, the optimal assortment is composed of only the most popular products (a common finding in the literature). We provide preliminary empirical evidence for one of the key drivers of our results: more eccentric products have higher probability of return—conditional on purchase. In light of our analytical findings and managerial insights, we conclude that retailers should take returns into account when merchandising.  相似文献   

8.
在两期销售环境下,研究了面向策略型消费者的在线零售商库存信息披露及联合定价、库存决策问题。考虑在线零售商库存信息共享和隐藏两种库存披露策略,构建了在线零售商两期销售利润模型。通过分析消费者的购买行为,讨论了在具有策略型消费者的市场中,在线零售商应如何选择库存信息披露策略,以及如何制定最优定价和库存决策。在此基础上,分析了相关参数对在线零售商决策及利润的影响。研究结果表明,在线零售商的最优定价及库存决策受消费者估值折扣系数和第二期定价策略的影响。特别地,当在线零售商选择第一期缺货时,更倾向于共享其库存水平信息;当在线零售商选择第二期缺货或者两期均不缺货时,消费者估值折扣系数存在一个阈值,当低于该阈值时,在线零售商会选择隐藏库存水平信息,当高于该阈值时,在线零售商会选择共享库存水平信息。  相似文献   

9.
随着线上线下融合的全渠道零售的兴起,越来越多的品牌商开始为顾客提供线上购买线下取货BOPS (Buy Online and Pickup in Store)的购物选择。本文考虑网络退货和渠道成本,基于网络渠道、实体渠道和BOPS渠道下的消费者效用函数构建品牌商开设BOPS渠道前后的利润模型,分析BOPS模式对品牌商需求分布和盈利能力的影响,研究定价和服务的最优决策。结果表明:(1)当网络退货率和BOPS渠道不便利程度之间满足特定关系时,开设BOPS渠道可使品牌商总需求增加、网络渠道和实体渠道的需求减少;(2)当网络退货率达到一定阈值或BOPS渠道很便利时,开设BOPS渠道可使品牌商总利润增加;(3)当网络退货率很低而网络渠道购物成本较高时,开设BOPS渠道可使品牌商获利更大;(4)在交通便利之处增设具有体验服务的顾客自提门店,不论网络渠道购物成本和网络退货率高低,甚至适当提升商品定价也可使品牌商有利可图。本研究可为品牌商实施BOPS全渠道战略提供一定的管理见解。  相似文献   

10.
本文针对网上在线销售易逝品的无缺陷退货现象,考虑了供应链的最优订购协调问题。利用一个两阶段动态规划来描述动态市场环境下网上销售商的两次订购行为,在假定在两个销售阶段都发生无缺陷退货现象的前提下,分别建立了集中和分散决策模型,同时设计了价格保护契约以实现供应链的协调运作。最后,利用数值仿真得出了一些重要的管理启示。通过研究发现:(1)当不确定性较大时,网上销售商需要在第1阶段多订购产品以应对需求风险,因此导致了较低的系统期望利润。并且,需求的不确定性越大,供应链协调越有价值。(2)当第1阶段或第2阶段退货率或两阶段退货率都增加时,两个阶段的最优订购量均减小。(3)对于需求波动性较高的产品,顾客的退货率越小或者可服务退货率越大,价值越高(即对供应链系统期望利润的提高越显著)。  相似文献   

11.
A return policy is commonly used by retailers to hedge for overstock risk. A number of research studies have developed models to identify when the manufacturer should accept returns. However, few of these studies consider the risk attitude of the decision maker, that is, existing papers assume that both the manufacturer and retailer are risk-neutral. Rather than ignore the risk attitude of the retailer and manufacturer, this paper relaxes this assumption and constructs a general returns model through the expected utility approach. An inventory theoretic model is developed and a menu of discount-return combinations is designed for the feasible solutions of a wholesale price discount and buyback price. It is shown that the decision to join a returns contact considerably depends on the utility functions for both the retailer and manufacturer. That is, the risk attitude is a core factor for the retailer and manufacturer to decide if to sign a returns contact, and without considering the factor in the model, the decision may be biased.  相似文献   

12.
Consumption-point programs have been commonly implemented in retail industries in efforts to promote sales and improve customer loyalty. In Korea, many retailers from different industries use a point-sharing policy to augment the conventional consumption-point program of each retailer. In a multi-retailer coalition under such a cooperative sales promotion policy, by purchasing from one coalition retailer, customers earn points that they can redeem points at other retailers in the coalition. On one hand, the introduction of this policy gives customers great flexibility for redeeming earned points, which can increase the demand at all retailers who promote the policy. On the other hand, the additional product costs associated with the points created by one retailer may spill over and be partly borne by other retailers, possibly distorting the coalition members’ equilibrium decisions under decentralized control. Under the general assumptions about the demand functions, we developed a model consisting of two retailers with fixed retail prices and addressed the retailers’ equilibrium decisions under a pure point-sharing policy. The findings suggest that the policy resulted in a cost spillover phenomenon. Then, we revealed that a pure point-sharing policy may fail to maximize the total profit of the coalition. Moreover, we showed that a pure point-sharing policy does not dominate the individual point scheme, which may explain the reason that point sharing is useful but not ubiquitously used in the real world. Our numerical examples also illustrate the way a pure point-sharing policy influences retailers’ profits when retail prices are decision variables. To improve the overall profit under the point-sharing policy further, we propose a target rebate contract to coordinate a pair of retailers. This contract can maximize the total profit and arbitrarily split the profit between retailers.  相似文献   

13.
Collaborative Forecasting and Replenishment (CFAR) is a new interorganizational system that enables retailers and manufacturers to forecast demand and schedule production jointly. The capabilities of CFAR exceed those of the traditional EDI because CFAR allows exchange of complex decision support models and manufacturer/retailer strategies. The proponents of CFAR claim that the fastest way for retailers and manufacturers to slash inventory costs and product shortages is by coordinating their decisions. The impact of CFAR on the supply chain using a model consisting of a manufacturer selling its product through two independent identical retailers is analyzed. The model assumes that the manufacturer doesn't face capacity constraints, the demand is stationary, and retailer prices are constant over time; the shortages are backordered at the manufacturer and retailers to isolate the effects of information sharing in CFAR. The most significant findings relate to the increase in the cost incurred by the nonparticipant in CFAR, the increase in the manufacturer's cost of serving the nonparticipant if the participant can obtain delivery guarantees in return for demand information sharing, and the incentives of the players to move towards universal retailer participation in CFAR. The findings are explained using the risk structure faced by the players in the supply chain. The managerial implications of the impact of CFAR on the supply chain structure are also discussed.  相似文献   

14.
针对由多个供应商和多个零售商组成的结构可变的供应链网络,分别在零售商之间基于订货量以及价格两种竞争方式下,分析了供应商均不采用返回策略、部分采用返回策略以及均采用返回策略六种情景下供应链网络的竞争绩效。研究发现当零售商基于订货量竞争时,供应商采用协调策略对于其零售商客户及供应链均为占优策略,零售商更换供应商的成本将会影响供应商的收益以及采用协调策略的积极性;当零售商之间基于价格竞争时,返回策略在一定程度上仍能够激励零售商增加订货量,且对供应链渠道的利润绩效及其稳定性均具有一定的改善作用。  相似文献   

15.
随着消费者消费观念的转变以及《消费者权益保护法》的普及,越来越多的电商企业开设体验店来改善消费者购物体验。本文针对由制造商(或供应商)和开设了体验店的线上零售商(或电商平台)组成的“线下体验,线上购买”O2O系统,考虑可能存在的消费者退货行为以及O2O系统成员企业之间的不对称信息,构建消费者预期效用函数,建立供应链两阶段动态博弈模型。通过模型求解,分析线上零售商开设体验店的可行条件及其对各个企业定价策略和消费者行为的影响,从制造商、O2O系统以及消费者剩余角度考察体验店的价值。研究发现:从线上零售商的角度,开设体验店存在可行条件,但在此可行条件内,体验店的开设总是能够有效提升制造商和供应链系统的期望利润;线上零售商开设体验店能够扩大市场占有率,并降低产品退货率和提升消费者剩余。最后,对原始模型进行了不同维度的扩展,分析产品体验影响消费者满意度和体验店设库存销售产品等情形下的体验店价值。  相似文献   

16.
In recent years, an increasing number of brick‐and‐mortar retailers have entered into the new brick‐and‐click era. Within this context, when a manufacturer presents a new product offering to a retailer, the ultimate decision is often made by the retailer regarding (1) whether to carry the new product, and (2) the channel outlet the product will be carried in (i.e., in‐store only, online‐exclusive, or brick‐and‐click). In response to this trend, we examine how a manufacturer may use product design to influence a dual‐channel retailer's outlet designation decision. This is the first study to investigate a manufacturer's optimal product design strategy when a brick‐and‐mortar retailer expands online. We demonstrate that, to induce the retailer to carry a new product both offline and online, it may not always be optimal for the manufacturer to enhance product quality (compared with when the retailer only operates offline). With the online store addition, the retailer may also be incentivized to adjust his participation criterion to a level less than what is determined by his outside option.  相似文献   

17.
针对制造商同时拥有零售渠道和网上直销渠道的双渠道供应链系统,在随机需求和联合促销情况下,对制造商和零售商之间的价格竞争和协调问题进行研究.研究表明价格的纳什均衡解存在,网上渠道的最优价格随零售商促销努力程度的增大而降低.当制造商分担促销成本的比例上升时,零售商促销的努力程度会增加.当比例值较低时,零售商的努力程度变化不大;当比例值超过一定数值时,零售商的努力程度会显著增加.回购契约能给制造商和零售商双方带来好处,但不能实现双渠道供应链的协调.  相似文献   

18.
In the newsvendor model, strategic consumers choose between buying the product at the regular price or waiting to try to buy the product at the discount price. Retailers can benefit from the ability to decrease strategic consumers’ perceived probability of finding a unit available at the discount price. Selling some inventory to an off-price retailer, who has a large number of thrift consumers, enables retailers to change consumers’ perceived probability of product availability at a reduced price, but at a cost of losing some strategic consumers to the off-price retailer. We show that without the off-price retailer’s exclusive consumers and even if the off-price retailer buys the product for a price below the retailer’s cost, the retailer can still be better-off with the off-price retailer. We also find that the retailer benefits more when the off-price retailer charges higher price for the product and has a large consumer segment of its own.  相似文献   

19.
《决策科学》2017,48(5):918-955
We study the distribution channel decision of a manufacturer who considers whether to add an online channel (direct channel) to its brick‐and‐mortar retailer (indirect channel). The retailer faces the opportunity to invest in store assistance to help consumers choose products and thus reduce product returns. Special attention is given to the impact of product returns and retailer's store assistance investment on manufacturer's dual channel decision. We examine conditions under which the manufacturer uses dual channels and how various relevant factors affect its channel decision under two settings, depending on whether the retailer has its own online store or not. When the retailer does not have its online store, we find that (i) the addition of the direct channel raises the wholesale price; (ii) the direct channel addition hurts the retailer if the nonreplacement rate is low; (iii) the manufacturer has a lower incentive to add the direct channel when the retailer's service cost is lower or its returns reduction rate from service investment is higher; and (iv) the manufacturer should treat its own returns handling cost as a key factor in its channel structure decision. In addition, when the retailer operates an online store, we find that the manufacturer may have an incentive to add a direct channel such that both firms own direct channels.  相似文献   

20.
考虑策略型消费者对产品估值的异质性和无缺陷退货行为,应用理性预期(RE)均衡构建了两期决策模型,引入产品的耐用性参数,得到了允许(不允许)无缺陷退货两种模式下零售商的定价区间和订货策略。研究发现,产品的耐用性越弱,零售商可制定的价格越高;高类型的消费者越多,零售商定价越高;产品折扣率越低,第二阶段购买的消费者越多;零售商允许消费者无缺陷退货时,消费者退货成本越低,零售商定价越高。在两种模式下,产品定价与其耐用性程度呈负相关,当产品具备高度潮流性特征时,不允许退货更占优势;随商品耐用性程度的提升,允许退货带来的优势逐渐明显,而且退货成本越低,允许退货优势越强;随产品耐用性参数增加,允许退货缓解策略型消费者消极影响的作用愈加明显,退货成本越高,缓解越有效。本文合理刻画了策略型消费者的行为,考虑了消费者跨期决策中产品耐用性的影响,同时考虑了现实中广泛存在的消费者无缺陷退货行为与零售商的退货补贴政策,从而为零售商的定价和订货退货决策提供了理论参考。  相似文献   

设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号