首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   91553篇
  免费   2941篇
  国内免费   3篇
管理学   12398篇
民族学   563篇
人才学   25篇
人口学   7213篇
丛书文集   530篇
教育普及   2篇
理论方法论   9479篇
现状及发展   1篇
综合类   2180篇
社会学   43201篇
统计学   18905篇
  2023年   504篇
  2021年   571篇
  2020年   1514篇
  2019年   2218篇
  2018年   2124篇
  2017年   3189篇
  2016年   2397篇
  2015年   2048篇
  2014年   2640篇
  2013年   18893篇
  2012年   2492篇
  2011年   2265篇
  2010年   2024篇
  2009年   2229篇
  2008年   2133篇
  2007年   1938篇
  2006年   2151篇
  2005年   2345篇
  2004年   2213篇
  2003年   1931篇
  2002年   2028篇
  2001年   2040篇
  2000年   1812篇
  1999年   1700篇
  1998年   1515篇
  1997年   1364篇
  1996年   1318篇
  1995年   1345篇
  1994年   1328篇
  1993年   1303篇
  1992年   1311篇
  1991年   1237篇
  1990年   1209篇
  1989年   1045篇
  1988年   1131篇
  1987年   1009篇
  1986年   915篇
  1985年   1081篇
  1984年   1138篇
  1983年   1021篇
  1982年   946篇
  1981年   869篇
  1980年   822篇
  1979年   871篇
  1978年   778篇
  1977年   714篇
  1976年   659篇
  1975年   638篇
  1974年   518篇
  1973年   441篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
911.
912.
Unions,PAC contributions,and the NAFTA vote   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Political action committees (PACs), especially those controlled by organized labor and business, have been shown to affect Congressional voting. We explore how PACs influenced the House of Representatives’ vote on the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). The NAFTA vote is analyzed because organized labor strongly opposed the treaty while business generally supported it and because of the straight-forward voting generated by its fast-track status. Probit analysis of a unique, unpublished data set containing information about PAC and non-PAC contributions to the 1992 House election campaigns demonstrates that Representatives who depended largely on labor PACs tended to oppose NAFTA, while Representatives who derived a large proportion of their campaign contributions from business PACs tended to favor its passage.  相似文献   
913.
914.
Violations of dominance in pricing judgments   总被引:1,自引:1,他引:0  
The dominance principle states that the judged price of gamble A should be equal to or greater than the judged price of gamble B whenever A's outcomes are equal to or better than the corresponding outcomes of B, holding everything else constant. Subjects often violate the dominance principle by assigning a higher price to a gamble with some probability of winning a positive amount, Y, otherwise zero, than to a superior gamble with the same chances of winning Y, otherwise winning X. Violations also occur with losses. Results are consistent with a configural-weight theory in which the decision weight for each outcome depends on the rank of the outcome with respect to the other outcomes in the lottery and the value of the outcome (zero vs. nonzero).The authors thank Shi-jie Chang, Duncan Luce, and Lisa Ordóñez for comments on an earlier draft. This research was supported by a National Science Foundation grant to the first author (BNS-8451368). Requests for reprints should be sent to Barbara Mellers, Dept. of Psychology, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720.  相似文献   
915.
916.
917.
918.
919.
The American diet has changed substantially over the last few decades. These changes provide a test for social theory and have substantial effects on the demand for various food products, thus impacting U.S. agriculture. In this paper a rapidly growing dietary choice—vegetarianism—is explored. Prevalence of various forms of vegetarianism is estimated in a representative sample of a suburban population and factors that influence choice of a vegetarian diet are examined. About 7 percent of the sample report they are vegetarians. The prevalence of vegetarianism is not influenced by age, gender, or education, but individuals holding traditional values are less likely to be vegetarian than others. There also is some evidence mat individuals holding altruistic values are more likely than others to be vegetarians.  相似文献   
920.
Making ends meet: perceptions of poverty in Sweden   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
During the era after the Second World War, Sweden has built a welfare system based on labor market participation and income maintenance. Low unemployment and decent wages are supposed to guarantee people a labor market income or income maintenance, which in turn should provide a proper standard for everyone. However, a rapid increase in unemployment and economic problems have made the future of the Swedish welfare state more uncertain than ever. These circumstances have, among other things, led to the suggestion that Sweden should abandon the income maintenance policy and create a social policy system with the more limited ambition of guaranteeing everyone a minimum income. In that case, one central question must be answered: what constitutes a decent minimum income in today's Sweden? Where should we draw the poverty line under which people will not be forced to live? These questions are central in the current debate. The consensual poverty line method is used in this article to derive a poverty line relevant for today's Sweden. The results shows that more than every fifth household has an income below the consensual poverty line. That is, they have an income that most Swedes would argue is too low to make ends meet. The level of the consensual poverty line was compared with the National Board of Health and Welfare's guidelines for social assistance. The consensual poverty line was shown to be more generous to small households and the norm for social assistance was more generous to larger households. Finally, the expenditure for guaranteeing all Swedish household a minimum income equal to the consensual poverty line was estimated: more than SEK 25 billion per year. The results in the article casts serious doubt on the ability of the Swedish welfare state to secure a decent income to all citizens.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号