首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   13671篇
  免费   180篇
  国内免费   29篇
管理学   1687篇
劳动科学   8篇
民族学   257篇
人才学   2篇
人口学   2446篇
丛书文集   908篇
理论方法论   639篇
综合类   1972篇
社会学   4569篇
统计学   1392篇
  2024年   4篇
  2023年   15篇
  2022年   72篇
  2021年   72篇
  2020年   57篇
  2019年   30篇
  2018年   1698篇
  2017年   1715篇
  2016年   1123篇
  2015年   127篇
  2014年   157篇
  2013年   187篇
  2012年   507篇
  2011年   1410篇
  2010年   1277篇
  2009年   1021篇
  2008年   1043篇
  2007年   1269篇
  2006年   254篇
  2005年   425篇
  2004年   381篇
  2003年   307篇
  2002年   199篇
  2001年   103篇
  2000年   81篇
  1999年   86篇
  1998年   35篇
  1997年   38篇
  1996年   60篇
  1995年   35篇
  1994年   20篇
  1993年   10篇
  1992年   12篇
  1991年   8篇
  1990年   9篇
  1989年   8篇
  1988年   15篇
  1987年   4篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   3篇
  1982年   1篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 9 毫秒
81.
文章基于ArcGIS-GeoDa平台,利用2008-2013年长江中游城市群面板数据,从人口、空间和产业城镇化角度刻画新型城镇化发展,实证检验长江中游城市群人口-空间-产业城镇化的空间自相关性及系统之间的时空耦合特征.研究表明:长江中游城市群新型城镇化水平偏低,空间城镇化和产业城镇化存在空间溢出效应,人口-空间-产业城镇化之间的耦合协调程度不高,但是各市(县)两极分化较明显.  相似文献   
82.
83.
Let mathbbF(2n+d)q2mathbb{F}^{(2nu+delta)}_{q^{2}} be a (2ν+δ)-dimensional unitary space of mathbbFq2mathbb{F}_{q^{2}} , where δ=0 or 1. In this paper we construct a family of inclusion matrices associated with subspaces of mathbbF(2n+d)q2mathbb{F}^{(2nu+delta)}_{q^{2}} , and exhibit its disjunct property. Moreover, we compare the ratio efficiency of this construction with others, and find it smaller under some conditions.  相似文献   
84.
中国零售银行经历了从初始形态向现代形态的发展变迁,典当、钱庄和票号等构成了中国零售银行的初始形态.新中国成立以后,中国的零售银行经历了曲折的制度变迁过程,合作金融、邮政金融等几经废立.但是改革开放以后,我国不断探索新时期适合中国国情的零售银行发展模式,积极推动零售银行制度改革和创新,包括改革合作金融体制,成立农村商业银行、村镇银行等新型金融机构,推动城市商业银行改制上市,为发展城乡社区型零售银行创造条件,同时改革邮政金融体制,成立了中国邮政储蓄银行,为我国大型零售银行的发展奠定了基础.中国零售银行制度在变迁中不断向前发展.我国零售银行的发展路径应该是组建社区型零售银行以及建立跨地域大型零售银行,实现对零售金融市场的全覆盖.  相似文献   
85.
We consider a confidence parametrization of binary information sources in terms of appropriate likelihood ratios. This parametrization is used for Bayesian belief updates and for the equivalent comparison of binary experiments. In contrast to the standard parametrization of a binary information source in terms of its specificity and its sensitivity, one of the two confidence parameters is sufficient for a Bayesian belief update conditional on a signal realization. We introduce a confidence-augmented receiver operating characteristic for comparisons of binary experiments for a class of “balanced” decision problems, relative to which the confidence order offers a higher resolution than Blackwell’s informativeness order.
Where observation is concerned, Chance favors only the prepared mind. —Louis Pasteur (1822–1895).
  相似文献   
86.
We formulate and investigate experimentally a model of how individuals choose between time sequences of monetary outcomes. The model assumes that a decision maker uses, sequentially, two criteria to screen options. Each criterion only permits a decision between some pairs of options, while the other options are incomparable according to that criterion. When the first criterion is not decisive, the decision maker resorts to the second criterion to select an alternative. We find that: (1) traditional economic models based on discounting alone cannot explain a significant (almost 30%) proportion of the data no matter how much variability in the discount functions is allowed; (2) our model, despite considering only a specific (exponential) form of discounting, can explain the data much better solely thanks to the use of the secondary criterion; (3) our model explains certain specific patterns in the choices of the “irrational” people. We reject the hypothesis that anomalous behavior is due simply to random “mistakes” around the basic predictions of discounting theories: deviations are not random and there are clear systematic patterns of association between “irrational” choices.  相似文献   
87.
A path scheme for a game is composed of a path, i.e., a sequence of coalitions that is formed during the coalition formation process and a scheme, i.e., a payoff vector for each coalition in the path. A path scheme is called population monotonic if a player’s payoff does not decrease as the path coalition grows. In this study, we focus on Shapley path schemes of simple games in which for every path coalition the Shapley value of the associated subgame provides the allocation at hand. Obviously, each Shapley path scheme of a game is population monotonic if and only if the Shapley allocation scheme of the game is population monotonic in the sense of Sprumont (Games Econ Behav 2:378–394, 1990). We prove that a simple game allows for population monotonic Shapley path schemes if and only if the game is balanced. Moreover, the Shapley path scheme of a specific path is population monotonic if and only if the first winning coalition that is formed along the path contains every minimal winning coalition. We also show that each Shapley path scheme of a simple game is population monotonic if and only if the set of veto players of the game is a winning coalition. Extensions of these results to other efficient probabilistic values are discussed.  相似文献   
88.
89.
We examine differences in the value of statistical life (VSL) across potential wage levels in panel data using quantile regressions with intercept heterogeneity. Latent heterogeneity is econometrically important and affects the estimated VSL. Our findings indicate that a reasonable average cost per expected life saved cut-off for health and safety regulations is 7 million to7 million to 8 million per life saved, but the VSL varies considerably across the labor force. Our results reconcile the previous discrepancies between hedonic VSL estimates and the values implied by theories linked to the coefficient of relative risk aversion. Because the VSL varies elastically with income, regulatory agencies should regularly update the VSL used in benefit assessments, increasing the VSL proportionally with changes in income over time.  相似文献   
90.
Using a large stated preference survey conducted across the U.S. and Canada, we assess differences in individual willingness to pay (WTP) for health risk reductions between the two countries. Our utility-theoretic choice model allows for systematically varying marginal utilities for avoided future time in different adverse health states (illness-years, recovered/remission years, and lost life-years). We find significant differences between Canadian and U.S. preferences. WTP also differs systematically with age, gender, education, and marital status, as well as a number of attitudinal and subjective health-perception variables. Age profiles for WTP are markedly different across the two countries. Canadians tend to display flatter age profiles, with peak WTP realized at older ages.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号