首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   8589篇
  免费   174篇
管理学   1329篇
民族学   32篇
人才学   1篇
人口学   798篇
丛书文集   29篇
教育普及   1篇
理论方法论   665篇
综合类   113篇
社会学   3709篇
统计学   2086篇
  2020年   126篇
  2019年   163篇
  2018年   229篇
  2017年   288篇
  2016年   205篇
  2015年   147篇
  2014年   199篇
  2013年   1429篇
  2012年   276篇
  2011年   254篇
  2010年   193篇
  2009年   187篇
  2008年   177篇
  2007年   207篇
  2006年   179篇
  2005年   184篇
  2004年   167篇
  2003年   165篇
  2002年   171篇
  2001年   212篇
  2000年   202篇
  1999年   186篇
  1998年   145篇
  1997年   135篇
  1996年   137篇
  1995年   118篇
  1994年   108篇
  1993年   108篇
  1992年   157篇
  1991年   125篇
  1990年   122篇
  1989年   119篇
  1988年   104篇
  1987年   98篇
  1986年   107篇
  1985年   116篇
  1984年   119篇
  1983年   134篇
  1982年   105篇
  1981年   90篇
  1980年   94篇
  1979年   101篇
  1978年   102篇
  1977年   87篇
  1976年   72篇
  1975年   71篇
  1974年   62篇
  1973年   62篇
  1972年   43篇
  1971年   51篇
排序方式: 共有8763条查询结果,搜索用时 453 毫秒
891.
 We characterize games which induce truthful revelation of the players’ preferences, either as dominant strategies (straightforward games) or in Nash equilibria. Strategies are statements of individual preferences on R n . Outcomes are social preferences. Preferences over outcomes are defined by a distance from a bliss point. We prove that g is straightforward if and only if g is locally constant or dictatorial (LCD), i.e., coordinate-wise either a constant or a projection map locally for almost all strategy profiles. We also establish that: (i) If a game is straightforward and respects unanimity, then the map g must be continuous, (ii) Straightforwardness is a nowhere dense property, (iii) There exist differentiable straightforward games which are non-dictatorial. (iv) If a social choice rule is Nash implementable, then it is straightforward and locally constant or dictatorial. Received: 30 December 1994/Accepted: 22 April 1996  相似文献   
892.
893.
The current challenges confronting career counselors require increased discourse regarding career counseling models. Some authors have initiated this discourse, but more participants are needed. The need also exists to communicate more aggressively the special expertise that career counselors bring to their work. As career counselors construct contemporary intervention models, they will need to engage in action research to demonstrate accountability and to document that their services are effective. Career counselors can embrace these activities by building on past practices to construct a vision for the future.  相似文献   
894.
This article shows how admission and enrollment processes affect the interpretation of simple validation studies of academic performance. In a competitive market for students, optimal behavior of admissions committees and applicants drives the simple correlation between test scores and performance toward zero, regardless of the relationship in the population of prospective students. Data from our university's MBA program support the prediction that applicants exhibit a higher correlation between test scores and undergraduate GPAs than do current students. This suggests that standard validation studies will understate the importance of GMAT scores in predicting performance of potential MBA students. (JEL C24 , I121 , C52 )  相似文献   
895.
896.
Survey researchers since Cannell have worried that respondents may take various shortcuts to reduce the effort needed to complete a survey. The evidence for such shortcuts is often indirect. For instance, preferences for earlier versus later response options have been interpreted as evidence that respondents do not read beyond the first few options. This is really only a hypothesis, however, that is not supported by direct evidence regarding the allocation of respondent attention. In the current study, we used a new method to more directly observe what respondents do and do not look at by recording their eye movements while they answered questions in a Web survey. The eye-tracking data indicate that respondents do in fact spend more time looking at the first few options in a list of response options than those at the end of the list; this helps explain their tendency to select the options presented first regardless of their content. In addition, the eye-tracking data reveal that respondents are reluctant to invest effort in reading definitions of survey concepts that are only a mouse click away or paying attention to initially hidden response options. It is clear from the eye-tracking data that some respondents are more prone to these and other cognitive shortcuts than others, providing relatively direct evidence for what had been suspected based on more conventional measures.  相似文献   
897.
We discuss the standard linear regression model with nonspherical disturbances, where some regressors are annihilated by considering only the residuals from an auxiliary regression, and where, analogous to the Frisch-Waugh procedure, the original GLS procedure is applied to the transformed data. We call this procedure pseudo-GLS and give conditions for pseudo-GL5 to be equal to genuine GLS. We also show via examples that these conditions are often violated in empirical applications, and that the Frisch-Waugh Theorem still “works” with nonspherical disturbances if efficient estimation is applied to both the original and the transformed data.  相似文献   
898.
899.
This paper describes a Bayesian approach to modelling carcinogenity in animal studies where the data consist of counts of the number of tumours present over time. It compares two autoregressive hidden Markov models. One of them models the transitions between three latent states: an inactive transient state, a multiplying state for increasing counts and a reducing state for decreasing counts. The second model introduces a fourth tied state to describe non‐zero observations that are neither increasing nor decreasing. Both these models can model the length of stay upon entry of a state. A discrete constant hazards waiting time distribution is used to model the time to onset of tumour growth. Our models describe between‐animal‐variability by a single hierarchy of random effects and the within‐animal variation by first‐order serial dependence. They can be extended to higher‐order serial dependence and multi‐level hierarchies. Analysis of data from animal experiments comparing the influence of two genes leads to conclusions that differ from those of Dunson (2000). The observed data likelihood defines an information criterion to assess the predictive properties of the three‐ and four‐state models. The deviance information criterion is appropriately defined for discrete parameters.  相似文献   
900.
Clinical trials and other types of studies often examine the effects of a particular treatment or experimental condition on a number of different response variables. Although the usual approach for analysing such data is to examine each variable separately, this can increase the chance of false positive findings. Bonferroni's inequality or Hotelling's T2 statistic can be employed to control the overall type I error rate, but these tests generally lack power for alternatives in which the treatment improves the outcome on most or all of the endpoints. For the comparison of independent groups, O'Brien (1984) developed a rank-sum type test that has greater power than the Bonferroni and T2 procedures when one treatment is uniformly better (i.e. for all endpoints) than the other treatment(s). In this paper we adapt the rank-sum test to studies involving paired data and demonstrate that it, too, has power advantages for such alternatives. Simulation results are described, and an example from a study measuring the effects of sleep loss on glucose metabolism is presented to illustrate the methodology.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号