全文获取类型
收费全文 | 10488篇 |
免费 | 6篇 |
专业分类
管理学 | 1515篇 |
民族学 | 99篇 |
人口学 | 2412篇 |
丛书文集 | 1篇 |
理论方法论 | 499篇 |
综合类 | 291篇 |
社会学 | 4482篇 |
统计学 | 1195篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 1篇 |
2019年 | 2篇 |
2018年 | 1658篇 |
2017年 | 1652篇 |
2016年 | 1077篇 |
2015年 | 39篇 |
2014年 | 37篇 |
2013年 | 48篇 |
2012年 | 321篇 |
2011年 | 1148篇 |
2010年 | 1045篇 |
2009年 | 781篇 |
2008年 | 821篇 |
2007年 | 1000篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 229篇 |
2004年 | 254篇 |
2003年 | 213篇 |
2002年 | 81篇 |
2001年 | 9篇 |
2000年 | 10篇 |
1999年 | 6篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 30篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 11篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 1篇 |
1974年 | 1篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
We show that Bayesian ex post aggregation is unstable with respect to refinements. Suppose a group of Bayesians use ex post
aggregation. Since it is a joint problem, each agent's problem is captured by the same model, but probabilities and utilities
may vary. If they analyze the same situation in more detail, their refined analysis should preserve their preferences among
acts. However, ex post aggregation could bring about a preference reversal on the group level. Ex post aggregation thus depends
on how much information is used and may keep oscillating (“flipping”) as one keeps adding more information.
Received: 16 April 2002/Accepted: 27 May 2002 相似文献
22.
Koji Takamiya 《Social Choice and Welfare》2003,20(1):77-83
In a general model of indivisible good allocation, S?nmez (1999) established that, whenever the core is nonempty for each
preference profile, if an allocation rule is strategy-proof, individually rational and Pareto optimal, then the rule is a
selection from the core correspondence, and the core correspondence must be essentially single-valued. This paper studies
the converse claim of this result. I demonstrate that whenever the preference domain satisfies a certain condition of `richness',
if the core correspondence is essentially single-valued, then any selection from the core correspondence is strategy-proof
(even weakly coalition strategy-proof, in fact). In particular, on the domain of preferences in which each individual has
strict preferences over his own assignments and there is no consumption externality, such an allocation rule is coalition
strategy-proof. And on this domain, coalition strategy-proofness is equivalent to Maskin monotonicity, an important property
in implementation theory.
Received: 22 February 2000/Accepted: 22 January 2002
I am grateful to Ryo-ichi Nagahisa, Shinji Ohseto, Hiroshi Ono, Tomoichi Shinotsuka and Shigehiro Serizawa for valuable comments.
And I am indebted to two anonymous referees for useful suggestions. Especially, I owe the present proof of Lemma 2 to one
referee. I also thank Yukihiko Funaki, Atsushi Kajii, Mamoru Kaneko, Eiichi Miyagawa, Tatsuyoshi Saijo, Manimay Sengupta,
Yves Sprumont, Yoshikatsu Tatamitani, Manabu Toda, Takashi Ui, Takehiko Yamato, Naoki Yoshihara and the participants of the
seminars in Hokkaido University, Kansai University, ISER (Osaka University), Otaru University of Commerce and Tsukuba University.
All errors are my own responsiblity. 相似文献
23.
24.
Frank De Zwart 《Theory and Society》2005,34(2):137-169
Governments around the world combat inequality by means of group-specific redistribution. Some pursue redistribution that benefits groups, but also wish to avoid accentuating or even recognizing group distinctions. This poses a dilemma that they try to resolve by adjusting the category system used to target redistribution. There are three types of adjustment: accommodation (the multicultural approach), denial (the ideal-typical liberal solution), and replacement (a compromise). In replacement the targets of redistributive policies are constructed to avoid accentuation or recognition of inconvenient group distinctions, but still allow redistribution that benefits these groups. Replacement is increasingly in demand around the world because the disadvantages of multiculturalism are becoming apparent while denial is hard to sustain in the face of group inequality. The actual effect of replacement is little researched and less understood, however. Does it resolve the dilemma of recognition? Two examples–India and Nigeria–where replacement has been tried ever since the 1950s cast doubt on its viability. 相似文献
25.
26.
There was a time in this fair land when the railroad did not run When the wild majestic mountains stood alone against the
sun Long before the white man and long before the wheel When the green dark forest was too silent to be real
For they looked into the future and what did they see They saw an iron road running from the sea to the sea Bringing the goods
to a young growing land All up through the seaports and into their hands
From “Canadian Railroad Trilogy” by Gordon Lightfoot
The authors thank CPR managers and union officials representing CPR employees for their cooperation and patience in explaining
the intricacies of the railroad industry. Special appreciation is extended to Jason Copping, Labour Relations Manager, for
his facilitating our initial access to the company. 相似文献
27.
We analyze the wealth ejfects of the Texaco racial discrimination lawsuit both on the shareholders of Texaco and its major
U.S. competitors. Employing a comprehensive data set which included every case docket entry and every Wall Street Journal
article on the case as an experimental stimulus, our findings suggest that the overall cost of the case to Texaco shareholders
exceeded $500 million, that Texaco's tribulations had little, if any, impact on the share prices of its major competitors,
and that Wall Street Journal coverage of the case was highly correlated with significant changes in Texaco stock prices. This
last finding provides significant support for Hite 's suppostion that newspaper editors “key ” on ex post stock price changes
in selecting the events to be covered in the next day's edition.
The authors are grateful to Kee Chung for helpful comments on earlier drafts and also acknowlege the help-ful assistance of
the staff of the law library at the Cecil C. Humphreys School of Law at The University of Memphis. 相似文献
28.
29.
30.
Russia’s role in ‘animation’ of the Kyoto Protocol was crucial. Its initial vacillation on ratification was predominantly
due to political bargaining with the EU. Domestic economic rationales [i.e. impacts of emission trading and Joint Implementation
(JI) projects] were important to a much lesser extent and environmental motives did not seem to play any role in the decision.
Since the Protocol entered into force, there have been significant delays in complete establishment of policy implementation
frameworks, which are necessary for Russia to start benefiting from JI and emission trading. Only recently, in 2007, have
GHG inventories and a national registry been established and the responsibilities for implementation of the Protocol and JI
among the government departments have been distributed only to a certain extent. Some constraints hindering JI projects, such
as vague legislation, an unfavourable economic climate, lack of commitment to JI projects, corruption, xenophobia, state and
agency ‘capture’ still remain.
相似文献