首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   26篇
  免费   0篇
丛书文集   2篇
理论方法论   8篇
社会学   13篇
统计学   3篇
  2022年   1篇
  2016年   1篇
  2014年   1篇
  2013年   3篇
  2012年   1篇
  2010年   1篇
  2009年   1篇
  2006年   1篇
  2005年   1篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   1篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1992年   1篇
  1987年   1篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   1篇
排序方式: 共有26条查询结果,搜索用时 468 毫秒
21.
The Borda Compromise states that, if one has to choose among five popular voting rules that are not Condorcet consistent, one should always give preference to the Borda rule over the four other rules. We assess the theoretical as well as the empirical support for the Borda Compromise. We find that, despite considerable differences between the properties of the theoretical framework and the characteristics of two sets of observed ranking data, all three analyses provide considerable support for the Borda Compromise.  相似文献   
22.
A procedure is developed to obtain representations for the probability of election outcomes with the Impartial Anonymous Culture Condition and the Maximal Culture Condition. The procedure is based upon a process of performing arithmetic with integers, while maintaining absolute precision with very large integer numbers. The procedure is then used to develop probability representations for a number of different voting outcomes, which have to date been considered to be intractable to obtain with the use of standard algebraic techniques. Received: 13 June 2000/Accepted: 22 January 2001  相似文献   
23.
A sample of n subjects is observed in each of two states, S1-and S2. In each state, a subject is in one of two conditions, X or Y. Thus, a subject may be recorded as showing a change if its condition in the two states is ‘Y,X’ or ‘X,Y’ and, otherwise, the condition is unchanged. We consider a Bayesian test of the null hypothesis that the probability of an ‘X,Y’ change exceeds that of a ‘Y,X’ change by amount kO. That is, we develop the posterior distribution of kO, the difference between the two probabilities and reject the null hypothesis if k lies outside the appropriate posterior probability interval. The performance of the method is assessed by Monte Carlo and other numerical studies and brief tables of exact critical values are presented  相似文献   
24.
This paper discusses the power p n of an n-member subgroup B n of an N-member voting body, N odd and 1 n N. In contrast to bloc voting, we assume that the members vote independently with equal probability for and against a given issue. Power p n is defined as the probability that the outcome of a vote changes if all members of B n reverse their votes. Theorems: p n + 1 = n for odd n < N; p n + p Nn = 1; P m + p n > p m + n if m + n < N; p n + 1/p n (n + 1)/n as N for fixed even n; for rational 0 > > 1, p N 2–1 sin–1 1/2 as N . A simple summation formula is given for p n .  相似文献   
25.
The Condorcet efficiency of Pairwise Proportional Lottery Rules (PPLR) is considered under various assumptions concerning the likelihood that given voters' preference profiles are observed on three alternatives. Representations are developed for the expected Condorcet efficiency under impartial culture, impartial anonymous culture, and a generalization to Pólya-Eggenberger distributions. PPLR is shown to be equivalent to a random selection process in the limit of voters under impartial culture. However, relatively small increases in social homogeneity, as measured by Kendall's Coefficient of Concordance, cause significant increases in the Condorcet efficiency of PPLR.Professor Berg's work was partly supported by the Swedish Research Council for the Humanities and Social Sciences.  相似文献   
26.
Consider an election in which each of the n voters casts a vote consisting of a strict preference ranking of the three candidates A, B, and C. In the limit as n→∞, which scoring rule maximizes, under the assumption of Impartial Anonymous Culture (uniform probability distribution over profiles), the probability that the Condorcet candidate wins the election, given that a Condorcet candidate exists? We produce an analytic solution, which is not the Borda Count. Our result agrees with recent numerical results from two independent studies, and contradicts a published result of Van Newenhizen (Economic Theory 2, 69–83. (1992)).  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号