排序方式: 共有53条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
11.
Milan Zafirovski 《The American Sociologist》2003,34(4):59-80
Methodologically, the most advanced social science discipline is considered economics, especially its neoclassical version.
A number of practitioners in the other social sciences, especially sociology and political science, perceive economics as
a scientific exemplar in methodological (and theoretical) terms. This methodological exemplar has been, particularly in the
last decades, attempted to emulate by some of these social scientists. The outcome of this emulation, by adopting and extending
its methods, of neoclassical economics in parts (but not all) of sociology, political science, and elsewhere has been rational
choice theory as a general social paradigm. This paper tries to show that many misapplications of the methodology of neoclassical
economics in rational choice theory have ensued from such methodological emulation. That neoclassical economics does not necessarily
contain or lead to a mathematical rational choice model is the core argument of this paper. The paper fills in a gap created
by the current literature’s focus on the methodological bases of mathematical rational choice theory in neoclassical economics. 相似文献
12.
Milan Zafirovski 《International Review of Sociology》2010,20(2):189-213
The article attempts to reanalyze the relationships between conservatism and fascism in a historical and comparative perspective. This analysis is premised on the view that to fully understand and explain conservatism requires reexamining its comparative-historical relations to fascism, and, alternatively, understanding and explaining the second presupposes taking account of the first. The thrust of the issue is whether and to what extent conservatism constitutes or develops into fascism, and, conversely, whether the latter represents or results from the former. The central argument and finding is that under certain social conditions and historical constellations conservatism eventually evolves into or functions as fascism. Alternatively, fascism universally represents and reproduces conservatism. 相似文献
13.
Globalization is constantly changing the appearance of the modern world. The most intense processes of integration are taking
place in Europe in the framework of the European Union (EU) enlargement. Though the formal process is more or less concluded,
the subtle and informal ones still have a long way to go. Social structures (institutions, organizations, norms, etc.) and
actions depend on the cultural environment in the narrowest sense of the word: human perceptions and values. This poses the
basic question whether the economic-cultural orientations of the new EU member states are compatible with imported social
structures. We have done an empirical research using Hofstede's cultural dimensions and European Values Study database for
26 European countries (23 EU member states, 2 candidate countries, and Northern Ireland as a separate entity). We have also
compared the differences and similarities by applying the Ward method (cluster analysis) on our 10 constructed variables. 相似文献
14.
15.
16.
Milan Z. Zafirovski 《The American Sociologist》2001,32(1):78-99
The article aims at reexamining the origins and character of economic sociology by comparison with rational choice within
the history of economic and social ideas, particularly neoclassical economic and classical sociological theory. Some suggestions
for a rational choice approach to economic sociology are particularly curious in that they tend to conflate the distinct characters
and origins of these two disciplines throughout this history and have in turn provided an impetus for this reexamination.
Modern rational choice theorists display a predilection for reducing economic (and, all) sociology into an economic approach
to human behavior, with many economic sociologists evincing some degree of lenience or benevolence vis-à-vis such tendencies.
Both tendencies do not seem justified in light of the different nature and origin of economic sociology and rational choice
in the history of social and economic ideas. Since the current literature lacks coherent attempts at specifying the nature
and historical roots of economic sociology versus those of rational choice, the article contributes toward filling in this
hole. 相似文献
17.
Milan Merkle 《Statistical Methods and Applications》1996,5(3):323-334
Summary Let
, whereX
i are i.i.d. random variables with a finite variance σ2 and
is the usual estimate of the mean ofX
i. We consider the problem of finding optimal α with respect to the minimization of the expected value of |S
2(σ)−σ2|k for variousk and with respect to Pitman's nearness criterion. For the Gaussian case analytical results are obtained and for some non-Gaussian
cases we present Monte Carlo results regarding Pitman's criteron.
This research was supported by Science Fund of Serbia, grant number 04M03, through Mathematical Institute, Belgrade. 相似文献
18.
Stefania Milan 《Information, Communication & Society》2015,18(8):887-900
This article develops a conceptual framework for understanding collective action in the age of social media, focusing on the role of collective identity and the process of its making. It is grounded on an interactionist approach that considers organized collective action as a social construct with communicative action at its core [Melucci, A. 1996. Challenging codes: Collective action in the information age. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press]. It explains how micromobilization is mediated by social media, and argues that social media play a novel broker role in the activists' meaning construction processes. Social media impose precise material constraints on their social affordances, which have profound implications in both the symbolic production and organizational dynamics of social action. The materiality of social media deeply affects identity building, in two ways: firstly, it amplifies the ‘interactive and shared’ elements of collective identity (Melucci, 1996), and secondly, it sets in motion a politics of visibility characterized by individuality, performance, visibility, and juxtaposition. The politics of visibility, at the heart of what I call ‘cloud protesting’, exacerbates the centrality of the subjective and private experience of the individual in contemporary mobilizations, and has partially replaced the politics of identity typical of social movements. The politics of visibility creates individuals-in-the-group, whereby the ‘collective’ is experienced through the ‘individual’ and the group is the means of collective action, rather than its end. 相似文献
19.
20.
Milan Zafirovski 《Journal for the theory of social behaviour》2019,49(4):499-518
The article places and analyzes the Chicago school of economics within the framework of Mannheim's sociology of knowledge or ideas that posits and documents social determinants of ideas and ideologies. This framework reveals the Chicago school as the explicit or implicit ideology and utopia of plutocracy, oligarchy and aristocracy in the sense of apologetics of these social classes and/or systems, thus being the class form of ‘apologetic economics’. Specifically, first, Chicago economics reveals itself as the collective‐unconscious apologetics of plutocracy, oligarchy and aristocracy. Second, it appears as the ‘collective‐conscious’ apologetics in this respect. In addition, it come close to the mostly covert collective‐unconscious or conscious apologetics of theocracy and fascism. The article aims to contribute to a better understanding of the social, in particular class, factors of Chicago and related schools of economics and generally of economic ideas, theories and policies by applying Mannheim's sociology of knowledge, especially its emphasis on the collective unconscious as the source of ideology. 相似文献