首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
  示例: 沙坡头地区,人工植被区,变化  检索词用空格隔开表示必须包含全部检索词,用“,”隔开表示只需满足任一检索词即可!
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   1333篇
  免费   7篇
管理学   282篇
民族学   11篇
人口学   92篇
丛书文集   5篇
理论方法论   154篇
综合类   5篇
社会学   553篇
统计学   238篇
  2024年   8篇
  2022年   9篇
  2021年   8篇
  2020年   18篇
  2019年   37篇
  2018年   37篇
  2017年   31篇
  2016年   26篇
  2015年   26篇
  2014年   34篇
  2013年   268篇
  2012年   36篇
  2011年   43篇
  2010年   35篇
  2009年   33篇
  2008年   31篇
  2007年   31篇
  2006年   25篇
  2005年   34篇
  2004年   28篇
  2003年   18篇
  2002年   38篇
  2001年   24篇
  2000年   23篇
  1999年   28篇
  1998年   19篇
  1997年   21篇
  1996年   19篇
  1995年   11篇
  1994年   11篇
  1993年   19篇
  1992年   13篇
  1991年   16篇
  1990年   12篇
  1989年   15篇
  1988年   13篇
  1987年   17篇
  1986年   12篇
  1985年   18篇
  1984年   18篇
  1983年   16篇
  1982年   16篇
  1981年   18篇
  1979年   9篇
  1978年   11篇
  1976年   14篇
  1975年   13篇
  1974年   8篇
  1972年   9篇
  1971年   10篇
排序方式: 共有1340条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
111.
Converse's definition of ideological contraint is expanded to provide for various respondent identified ideological dimensions rather than an all encompassing liberal-conservative dimension. Using this redefinition a sample of adults is shown to have high levels of ideological constraint. Ideological constraint is shown to vary with the degree of cognitive complexity and the degree of preference evaluability. The latter is a new concept that suggests that some issues will be easier for a respondent to demonstrate constraint on depending upon the availability and applicability of preference criteria. Salience is also shown to have a positive relationship with ideological constraint, but only when preference evaluability is high.  相似文献   
112.
Recently several authors have proposed stochastic evolutionary models for the growth of complex networks that give rise to power-law distributions. These models are based on the notion of preferential attachment leading to the “rich get richer” phenomenon. Despite the generality of the proposed stochastic models, there are still some unexplained phenomena, which may arise due to the limited size of networks such as protein, e-mail, actor and collaboration networks. Such networks may in fact exhibit an exponential cutoff in the power-law scaling, although this cutoff may only be observable in the tail of the distribution for extremely large networks. We propose a modification of the basic stochastic evolutionary model, so that after a node is chosen preferentially, say according to the number of its inlinks, there is a small probability that this node will become inactive. We show that as a result of this modification, by viewing the stochastic process in terms of an urn transfer model, we obtain a power-law distribution with an exponential cutoff. Unlike many other models, the current model can capture instances where the exponent of the distribution is less than or equal to two. As a proof of concept, we demonstrate the consistency of our model empirically by analysing the Mathematical Research collaboration network, the distribution of which has been shown to be compatible with a power law with an exponential cutoff.  相似文献   
113.
114.
115.
116.
Assuming a statistical model in which the joint distribution of the unobservable errors is drawn from independent univariate Student t's that are identically and symmetrically distributed, the sampling performance of traditional robust estimators and a family of Stein-like estimators are compared and evaluated. These results suggest that under thick-tailed distributions, the relative sampling performances and risk characteristics for a range of nonconventional Stein estimators remains approximately the same as in the case of their normal counterparts. The empirical risk implications of misspecifying the error distribution are investigated.  相似文献   
117.
A class of decisions, asset mix decisions made by pension fund managers, which exhibit characteristics of both programmed and strategic choices is examined in this paper. The decisions are classified using the scheme developed by Mintzberg et al., (1976) to highlight the circumstances under which strategic decisions may be programmed. The types of strategic decisions which lend themselves to programming are considered. The advantages and disadvantages of programming strategic decisions are also discussed.  相似文献   
118.
Bill George 《经理人》2008,(12):58-58
企业的商业伦理应该在全球范围内保持一致,还是应该根据具体的经营环境进行调整呢?许多人认为,企业的伦理准则应该与经营地的实际情况相契合,推崇“情境伦理”,即根据复杂多变的实际环境,灵活采取相应的实用性伦理准则。  相似文献   
119.
Given i.i.d. observations x1,x2,x3,...,xn drawn from a mixture of normal terms, one is often interested in determining the number of terms in the mixture and their defining parameters. Although the problem of determining the number of terms is intractable under the most general assumptions, there is hope of elucidating the mixture structure given appropriate caveats on the underlying mixture. This paper examines a new approach to this problem based on the use of Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) based pruning of data driven mixture models which are obtained from resampled data sets. Results of the application of this procedure to artificially generated data sets and a real world data set are provided.  相似文献   
120.
Let \(\mathbb{N } = \{1, 2, 3, \ldots \}\) . Let \(\{X, X_{n}; n \in \mathbb N \}\) be a sequence of i.i.d. random variables, and let \(S_{n} = \sum _{i=1}^{n}X_{i}, n \in \mathbb N \) . Then \( S_{n}/\sqrt{n} \Rightarrow N(0, \sigma ^{2})\) for some \(\sigma ^{2} < \infty \) whenever, for a subsequence \(\{n_{k}; k \in \mathbb N \}\) of \(\mathbb N \) , \( S_{n_{k}}/\sqrt{n_{k}} \Rightarrow N(0, \sigma ^{2})\) . Motivated by this result, we study the central limit theorem along subsequences of sums of i.i.d. random variables when \(\{\sqrt{n}; n \in \mathbb N \}\) is replaced by \(\{\sqrt{na_{n}};n \in \mathbb N \}\) with \(\lim _{n \rightarrow \infty } a_{n} = \infty \) . We show that, for given positive nondecreasing sequence \(\{a_{n}; n \in \mathbb N \}\) with \(\lim _{n \rightarrow \infty } a_{n} = \infty \) and \(\lim _{n \rightarrow \infty } a_{n+1}/a_{n} = 1\) and given nondecreasing function \(h(\cdot ): (0, \infty ) \rightarrow (0, \infty )\) with \(\lim _{x \rightarrow \infty } h(x) = \infty \) , there exists a sequence \(\{X, X_{n}; n \in \mathbb N \}\) of symmetric i.i.d. random variables such that \(\mathbb E h(|X|) = \infty \) and, for some subsequence \(\{n_{k}; k \in \mathbb N \}\) of \(\mathbb N \) , \( S_{n_{k}}/\sqrt{n_{k}a_{n_{k}}} \Rightarrow N(0, 1)\) . In particular, for given \(0 < p < 2\) and given nondecreasing function \(h(\cdot ): (0, \infty ) \rightarrow (0, \infty )\) with \(\lim _{x \rightarrow \infty } h(x) = \infty \) , there exists a sequence \(\{X, X_{n}; n \in \mathbb N \}\) of symmetric i.i.d. random variables such that \(\mathbb E h(|X|) = \infty \) and, for some subsequence \(\{n_{k}; k \in \mathbb N \}\) of \(\mathbb N \) , \( S_{n_{k}}/n_{k}^{1/p} \Rightarrow N(0, 1)\) .  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号