首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   90091篇
  免费   2981篇
  国内免费   4篇
管理学   12377篇
民族学   550篇
人才学   26篇
人口学   6886篇
丛书文集   524篇
教育普及   1篇
理论方法论   9534篇
综合类   2102篇
社会学   42162篇
统计学   18914篇
  2023年   511篇
  2021年   580篇
  2020年   1520篇
  2019年   2233篇
  2018年   2084篇
  2017年   3163篇
  2016年   2390篇
  2015年   2063篇
  2014年   2649篇
  2013年   19034篇
  2012年   2334篇
  2011年   2185篇
  2010年   1968篇
  2009年   2204篇
  2008年   2074篇
  2007年   1874篇
  2006年   2133篇
  2005年   2277篇
  2004年   2178篇
  2003年   1904篇
  2002年   2016篇
  2001年   1995篇
  2000年   1766篇
  1999年   1678篇
  1998年   1502篇
  1997年   1343篇
  1996年   1305篇
  1995年   1316篇
  1994年   1296篇
  1993年   1277篇
  1992年   1259篇
  1991年   1195篇
  1990年   1157篇
  1989年   1007篇
  1988年   1088篇
  1987年   968篇
  1986年   875篇
  1985年   1043篇
  1984年   1112篇
  1983年   974篇
  1982年   919篇
  1981年   843篇
  1980年   805篇
  1979年   850篇
  1978年   761篇
  1977年   685篇
  1976年   646篇
  1975年   630篇
  1974年   506篇
  1973年   421篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 109 毫秒
81.
The socio-economic literature has focused much on how overall inequality in income distribution (frequently measured by the Gini coefficient) undermines the “trickle down” effect. In other words, the higher the inequality in the income distribution, the lower is the growth elasticity of poverty. However, with the publication of Piketty’s magnum opus (2014), and a subsequent study by Chancel and Piketty (2017) of evolution of income inequality in India since 1922, the focus has shifted to the income disparity between the richest 1% (or 0.01%) and the bottom 50%. Their central argument is that the rapid growth of income at the top end of millionaires and billionaires is a by-product of growth. The present study extends this argument by linking it to poverty indices in India. Based on the India Human Development Survey 2005–12 – a nationwide panel survey-we examine the links between poverty and income inequality, especially in the upper tail relative to the bottom 50%, state affluence (measured in per capita income) and their interaction or their joint effect. Another feature of our research is that we analyse their effects on the FGT class of poverty indices. The results are similar in as much as direction of association is concerned but the elasticities vary with the poverty index. The growth elasticities are negative and significant for all poverty indices. In all three cases, the disparity between the income share of the top 1% and share of the bottom 50% is associated with greater poverty. These elasticities are much higher than the (absolute) income elasticities except in the case of the poverty gap. The largest increase occurs in the poverty gap squared – a 1% greater income disparity is associated with a 1.24% higher value of this index. Thus the consequences of even a small increase in the income disparity are alarming for the poorest.  相似文献   
82.
83.
Reuband’s article purports to report empirical results that seem to contradict the widely held view of mail surveys. This assertion is made possible only by an unclear statement of hypotheses and a selective perception of the literature. The data analysis is based on techniques from the 1960s and 1970s; modern methods are not even mentioned. Although all the results reported in the article are based on local surveys conducted by a university institute, these are generalized to national surveys in general. The main points of this critique are methodological: careless literature review, lack of concrete hypotheses, inefficient data analysis and generalizations without empirical foundation.  相似文献   
84.
85.
CORRUPTION: TOP DOWN OR BOTTOM UP?   总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3  
This article studies the impact of corruption on an economy with a hierarchical government. In particular, we study whether centralizing corruption within the higher level of government increases or decreases the total amount of corruption. We show that when the after-tax relative profitability of the formal sector as compared to that of the informal sector is high enough, adding a layer of government increases the total amount of corruption. By contrast, for high-enough public wages and/or an efficient monitoring technology of the bureaucratic system, centralization of corruption at the top of the government hierarchy redistributes bribe income from the lower level to the upper level. In the process, total corruption is reduced and the formal sector of the economy expands.  相似文献   
86.
87.
This study replicated and extended previously reported sex differences involving both viewer and target in the recognition of threatening facial expressions. Based on the assumption that the evolved cognitive mechanisms mediating anger recognition would have been designed by natural selection to operate quickly in the interests of survival, brief tachistoscopic presentation of stimulus photographs was used. Additionally, in contrast to prior published studies, the statistical methods of signal detection research were used to control for the confounding effects of non-random guessing. The main hypothesis, that anger posed by males would be more accurately perceived than anger posed by females, was supported. A secondary hypothesis, that female-posed anger would be more accurately perceived by women than by men, received partial support. Testosterone levels, measured inferentially in terms of diurnal cycles, failed to show the hypothesized positive relationship to accuracy of anger perception.  相似文献   
88.
89.
90.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号