首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   90464篇
  免费   2960篇
  国内免费   3篇
管理学   12457篇
民族学   543篇
人才学   25篇
人口学   6928篇
丛书文集   520篇
教育普及   3篇
理论方法论   9498篇
综合类   2117篇
社会学   42464篇
统计学   18872篇
  2023年   512篇
  2021年   576篇
  2020年   1520篇
  2019年   2238篇
  2018年   2081篇
  2017年   3173篇
  2016年   2384篇
  2015年   2064篇
  2014年   2644篇
  2013年   18952篇
  2012年   2364篇
  2011年   2162篇
  2010年   1966篇
  2009年   2198篇
  2008年   2046篇
  2007年   1846篇
  2006年   2098篇
  2005年   2287篇
  2004年   2155篇
  2003年   1895篇
  2002年   1984篇
  2001年   2015篇
  2000年   1795篇
  1999年   1717篇
  1998年   1500篇
  1997年   1350篇
  1996年   1316篇
  1995年   1333篇
  1994年   1310篇
  1993年   1284篇
  1992年   1288篇
  1991年   1197篇
  1990年   1186篇
  1989年   1033篇
  1988年   1114篇
  1987年   1003篇
  1986年   889篇
  1985年   1061篇
  1984年   1138篇
  1983年   1005篇
  1982年   928篇
  1981年   863篇
  1980年   811篇
  1979年   888篇
  1978年   774篇
  1977年   693篇
  1976年   651篇
  1975年   637篇
  1974年   519篇
  1973年   437篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
81.
The socio-economic literature has focused much on how overall inequality in income distribution (frequently measured by the Gini coefficient) undermines the “trickle down” effect. In other words, the higher the inequality in the income distribution, the lower is the growth elasticity of poverty. However, with the publication of Piketty’s magnum opus (2014), and a subsequent study by Chancel and Piketty (2017) of evolution of income inequality in India since 1922, the focus has shifted to the income disparity between the richest 1% (or 0.01%) and the bottom 50%. Their central argument is that the rapid growth of income at the top end of millionaires and billionaires is a by-product of growth. The present study extends this argument by linking it to poverty indices in India. Based on the India Human Development Survey 2005–12 – a nationwide panel survey-we examine the links between poverty and income inequality, especially in the upper tail relative to the bottom 50%, state affluence (measured in per capita income) and their interaction or their joint effect. Another feature of our research is that we analyse their effects on the FGT class of poverty indices. The results are similar in as much as direction of association is concerned but the elasticities vary with the poverty index. The growth elasticities are negative and significant for all poverty indices. In all three cases, the disparity between the income share of the top 1% and share of the bottom 50% is associated with greater poverty. These elasticities are much higher than the (absolute) income elasticities except in the case of the poverty gap. The largest increase occurs in the poverty gap squared – a 1% greater income disparity is associated with a 1.24% higher value of this index. Thus the consequences of even a small increase in the income disparity are alarming for the poorest.  相似文献   
82.
83.
Reuband’s article purports to report empirical results that seem to contradict the widely held view of mail surveys. This assertion is made possible only by an unclear statement of hypotheses and a selective perception of the literature. The data analysis is based on techniques from the 1960s and 1970s; modern methods are not even mentioned. Although all the results reported in the article are based on local surveys conducted by a university institute, these are generalized to national surveys in general. The main points of this critique are methodological: careless literature review, lack of concrete hypotheses, inefficient data analysis and generalizations without empirical foundation.  相似文献   
84.
85.
CORRUPTION: TOP DOWN OR BOTTOM UP?   总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3  
This article studies the impact of corruption on an economy with a hierarchical government. In particular, we study whether centralizing corruption within the higher level of government increases or decreases the total amount of corruption. We show that when the after-tax relative profitability of the formal sector as compared to that of the informal sector is high enough, adding a layer of government increases the total amount of corruption. By contrast, for high-enough public wages and/or an efficient monitoring technology of the bureaucratic system, centralization of corruption at the top of the government hierarchy redistributes bribe income from the lower level to the upper level. In the process, total corruption is reduced and the formal sector of the economy expands.  相似文献   
86.
87.
Multi-valued strategy-proof social choice rules   总被引:10,自引:4,他引:6  
In this paper we introduce a new definition of strategy-proofness for multi-valued social choice correspondences. We prove two Gibbard-Satterthwaite type results for strategy-proof social choice correspondences. These results show that allowing multiple outcomes as social choices will not necessarily lead to an escape from the Gibbard-Satterthwaite impossibility theorem. Received: 24 January 2001/Accepted: 19 March 2001  相似文献   
88.
This study replicated and extended previously reported sex differences involving both viewer and target in the recognition of threatening facial expressions. Based on the assumption that the evolved cognitive mechanisms mediating anger recognition would have been designed by natural selection to operate quickly in the interests of survival, brief tachistoscopic presentation of stimulus photographs was used. Additionally, in contrast to prior published studies, the statistical methods of signal detection research were used to control for the confounding effects of non-random guessing. The main hypothesis, that anger posed by males would be more accurately perceived than anger posed by females, was supported. A secondary hypothesis, that female-posed anger would be more accurately perceived by women than by men, received partial support. Testosterone levels, measured inferentially in terms of diurnal cycles, failed to show the hypothesized positive relationship to accuracy of anger perception.  相似文献   
89.
90.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号