首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   10650篇
  免费   275篇
  国内免费   2篇
管理学   1732篇
民族学   48篇
人才学   4篇
人口学   888篇
丛书文集   39篇
理论方法论   1014篇
综合类   113篇
社会学   5371篇
统计学   1718篇
  2020年   144篇
  2019年   202篇
  2018年   214篇
  2017年   265篇
  2016年   237篇
  2015年   175篇
  2014年   240篇
  2013年   1769篇
  2012年   283篇
  2011年   285篇
  2010年   238篇
  2009年   234篇
  2008年   290篇
  2007年   264篇
  2006年   291篇
  2005年   294篇
  2004年   235篇
  2003年   212篇
  2002年   232篇
  2001年   225篇
  2000年   221篇
  1999年   199篇
  1998年   187篇
  1997年   154篇
  1996年   157篇
  1995年   157篇
  1994年   184篇
  1993年   173篇
  1992年   178篇
  1991年   195篇
  1990年   210篇
  1989年   174篇
  1988年   190篇
  1987年   169篇
  1986年   156篇
  1985年   173篇
  1984年   180篇
  1983年   158篇
  1982年   124篇
  1981年   99篇
  1980年   100篇
  1979年   125篇
  1978年   105篇
  1977年   85篇
  1976年   96篇
  1975年   64篇
  1974年   91篇
  1973年   61篇
  1972年   50篇
  1971年   50篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 875 毫秒
891.
We describe the application of tools from statistical mechanics to analyse the dynamics of various classes of supervised learning rules in perceptrons. The character of this paper is mostly that of a cross between a biased non-encyclopaedic review and lecture notes: we try to present a coherent and self-contained picture of the basics of this field, to explain the ideas and tricks, to show how the predictions of the theory compare with (simulation) experiments, and to bring together scattered results. Technical details are given explicitly in an appendix. In order to avoid distraction we concentrate the references in a final section. In addition this paper contains some new results: (i) explicit solutions of the macroscopic equations that describe the error evolution for on-line and batch learning rules; (ii) an analysis of the dynamics of arbitrary macroscopic observables (for complete and incomplete training sets), leading to a general Fokker–Planck equation; and (iii) the macroscopic laws describing batch learning with complete training sets. We close the paper with a preliminary expose´ of ongoing research on the dynamics of learning for the case where the training set is incomplete (i.e. where the number of examples scales linearly with the network size).  相似文献   
892.
Implementation of a full Bayesian non-parametric analysis involving neutral to the right processes (apart from the special case of the Dirichlet process) has been difficult for two reasons: first, the posterior distributions are complex and therefore only Bayes estimates (posterior expectations) have previously been presented; secondly, it is difficult to obtain an interpretation for the parameters of a neutral to the right process. In this paper we extend Ferguson & Phadia (1979) by presenting a general method for specifying the prior mean and variance of a neutral to the right process, providing the interpretation of the parameters. Additionally, we provide the basis for a full Bayesian analysis, via simulation, from the posterior process using a hybrid of new algorithms that is applicable to a large class of neutral to the right processes (Ferguson & Phadia only provide posterior means). The ideas are exemplified through illustrative analyses.  相似文献   
893.
Archival data on over 15,000 contributors to 33management journals are used to examine productivitydifferences among scholars in different areas ofmanagement. The results suggest that a fragmentedpublication network offers specialists from different areasdissimilar publication opportunities and experiences,and may contribute to varying levels of publicationproductivity among authors. The implications of our results for future research and facultyevaluation processes are explored.  相似文献   
894.
895.
Utilisant les données du recensement de 1931 ainsi que d'entrevues avec des retraités d'Hamilton, en Ontario, qui recevaient un salaire durant la Grande Dépression, l'auteur examine les affirmations selon lesquelles les crises économiques sapent ou renforcent, ou n'affectent pas nécessairement la hiérarchie traditionnelle. Cela parce que, respectivement, elles substituent des ouvriers moins qualifiés, à meilleur marché aux autres ouvriers, elles privilégient les travailleurs hautement qualifiés ou elles affectent différemment les industries et occupations parmi lesquelles les ouvriers de différentes conditions sociales sont ségrégués. Le plus notable est qu'aucun résultat n'était marqué ni consistant en ce qui concerne les situations professionnelles, lâge, le sexe et l'ethnie sur tout type de privation. Cependant, certains types de privation montraient certaines différences de rangs. Donc, lorsque la profession était contrôlée dans les données du recensement, le modéle le plus commun était que les femmes travaillaient plus que les hommes, seulement lorsqu'en fait elles gagnaient moins. Cela suggère la «substitution» du travail à bon marché des femmes à celui des hommes et, en conséquence, l'ébranlement des privilèges de ces derniers. Par contre, selon les données tirées des entrevues, plus on était jeune et plus on attendait pour obtenir un travail rémunéréà temps plein, plus il était difficile d'en trouver, et plus le salaire était bas. Cela suggère que des privilèges associés avec lâge étaient renforcés durant la Dépression. Néanmoins, il y avait aussi ségrégation industrielle et occupationnelle, selon lâge, l'ethnie et le sexe, ce qui peut expliquer en partie pourquoi la plupart des différences de rangs sociaux n'étaient ni sapées ni renforcées. L'auteur a aussi trouvé peu de différences de rangs sociaux dans les réactions des ouvriers à la crise et, par conséquent, peu d'évidences quant au processus d'homogénéisation/radicalisation de la gauche associé avec l'hypothèse de la première affirmation ou à la diffé-renciation/conservatisme des ouvriers hautement qualifiés et à la radicalisation des ouvriers moins qualifiés associés avec l'affir-mation de l'hypothèse de renforcissement. Using data from the 1931 Census and interviews with Hamilton, Ontario retirees who worked for pay during the Great Depression, the author examines claims that economic crises undermine, strengthen, or need not affect traditional status hierarchies; because, respectively, they substitute “cheaper” low-status workers for others; privilege high-status workers; or differentially affect industries and occupations where workers of different status are segregated. The most remarkable result was that there were no such strong and consistent results for any of occupational status, age, gender and ethnicity on all types of deprivation. However, there was evidence for some status differences on some types of deprivation. Thus, when occupation was controlled in the census data, the most common pattern was for women to work more than men only when they in fact earned less. This suggests the “substitution” of the cheaper labour of women for that of men, and therefore the undermining of the privileges of men. On the other hand, in the interview data, the younger one was and the later one attempted to obtain full-time, paid work, the more difficulty one had finding it, and the lower one's wages were. This suggests that some age privileges were strengthened during the Depression. Nevertheless, there was also much industrial and occupational segregation, by age and ethnicity as well as gender, and this may partly explain why most status differences were neither undermined nor strengthened. The author also found few status differences in workers' responses to the crisis, and therefore little evidence for either the homogenization/left-radicalization process associated with the undermining hypothesis or the differentiation/conservatizing of high-status workers and radicalization of low-status workers associated with the strengthening claim.  相似文献   
896.
This article contends that one key to understanding different forms of work organization lies in the nature of the products being created. Product characteristics are proposed to be critical determinants of the type of human capital, either general or firm specific. Following from prior theory, labor market barriers develop based on type of human capital. These barriers then have a direct bearing on employee rewards. The nature of the product distinction is captured with a comparison of two product-types (goods and services) conceived as theoretically distinct. General skills are hypothesized to be more important in the service-producing sector, while firm-specific skills are hypothesized to be more important in the goods-producing sector. Empirical analyses using the 1991 General Social Survey compare workers in the service-producing and goods-producing sectors to illustrate differences in the salience of firm-specific and general skills. Two hypotheses are supported. Firm-specific skills have a stronger effect on earnings in manufacturing industries than in service industries. Also, skills acquired from on-the-job training, when compared with other skills, are more weakly related to service employee rewards. These distinctions between sectors suggest insights into structures unique to the service employment workplace.  相似文献   
897.
This study examined the impact of information subsidies on media coverage during a crisis. Using the July 2006 Israel–Lebanon conflict as a backdrop, this research reviewed access that U.S. military public affairs officers provided the media and analyzed subsequent coverage for the presence of the military's message. Coverage was more neutral to positive than negative. Items containing organizational messages were more positive; those quoting practitioner-facilitated sources introduced organizational messages into coverage and generated more positive coverage. Access to information subsidies had a positive impact on coverage and aided in the successful transfer of attribute salience from practitioners to the media.  相似文献   
898.
This paper explores methods to study trust. In a variety of settings, answers to survey questions and choices in a trust game are obtained from student sample pools. Some subjects are approached by mail and execute their task at home whereas others participate in classroom experiments. No differences between the results obtained by these methods are observed. Furthermore, one additional group plays the trust game with purely hypothetical payments, and another receives random lottery payments. This changes trust behavior dramatically, whereas trustworthiness is unaffected. Subjects without any financial incentives exhibit less trust and their trust choices are significantly correlated with survey trust answers. There is no such correlation for the corresponding choices with real payments.  相似文献   
899.
Many prominent bioethicists argue that positive consequences follow from avoiding disability in offspring by preconceptual, preimplantation or prenatal means. This paper critiques two variants of these positions: ‘Open future’ arguments that avoiding disability is in the interest of the persons who will be affected by it if born and ‘non‐person‐affecting’ claims that failures to avoid disability in offspring are wrong for reasons independent of their effect on affected offspring. Difficulties with both person‐affecting and non‐person‐affecting accounts are discussed in support of the charge that these arguments do not show that positive consequences follow from disability avoidance.  相似文献   
900.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号