全文获取类型
收费全文 | 157篇 |
免费 | 3篇 |
专业分类
管理学 | 31篇 |
人口学 | 4篇 |
丛书文集 | 2篇 |
理论方法论 | 9篇 |
综合类 | 58篇 |
社会学 | 21篇 |
统计学 | 35篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 1篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 11篇 |
2019年 | 2篇 |
2018年 | 6篇 |
2017年 | 2篇 |
2016年 | 4篇 |
2015年 | 5篇 |
2014年 | 5篇 |
2013年 | 10篇 |
2012年 | 14篇 |
2011年 | 13篇 |
2010年 | 4篇 |
2009年 | 10篇 |
2008年 | 6篇 |
2007年 | 16篇 |
2006年 | 19篇 |
2005年 | 7篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 3篇 |
2002年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 1篇 |
1999年 | 3篇 |
1996年 | 2篇 |
1995年 | 3篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有160条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
111.
The main aim of this article is to investigate the behavioral consequences of the provision of subject-specific information in the group effort levels chosen by players in an experimental CPR game. We examine two basic treatments, one with incomplete information and the other with complete information. In the former, subjects are informed only about their own individual payoffs and the aggregate extraction effort level of the group, and in the latter they are also informed about the individual effort levels and payoffs of each subject. Given this setting, the basic question we attempt to answer is: Will the provision of subject-specific performance information (i.e. individual’s effort levels and payoffs) improve or worsen the tragedy of the commons (i.e. an exploitation effort level greater than the socially optimum level)? In order to motivate our hypotheses and explain our experimental results at the individual level, we make use of the theory of learning in games, which goes beyond standard non-cooperative game theory, allowing us to explore the three basic benchmarks in the commons context: Nash equilibrium, Pareto efficient, and open access outcomes. We use several learning and imitation theoretical models that are based on contrasting assumptions about the level of rationality and the information available to subjects, namely: best response, imitate the average, mix of best response and imitate the average, imitate the best and follow the exemplary learning rules. Finally, in order to econometrically test the hypotheses formulated from the theoretical predictions we use a random-effects model to assess the explanatory power of the different selected behavioral learning and imitation rules. 相似文献
112.
This paper explores the role of mortality in the long transition from Malthusian stagnation to sustained economic growth. An endogenous child mortality rate that varies inversely with parents standard of living is added to the framework in Galor and Weil (AER 2000). In our version of the model, the transition from stagnation to growth, triggered by an exogenous shock to technology, comprises a mortality revolution succeeded by a demographic transition.This paper has benefitted from discussions with and suggestions made by KarlGunnar Persson, Christian Schultz, and, particularly, Christian Groth at the University of Copenhagen. I gratefully acknowledge the insightful criticisms of two anonymous referees, and I thank Paula Madsen for English proof-reading. Responsible editor: Alessandro Cigno. 相似文献
113.
“Living in sin” and marriage: A matching model 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
This paper develops a two sided matching model of premarital cohabitation and marriage in which premarital cohabitation serves
as a period of learning. We solve for the optimal policy to be followed by individuals by treating the model as a three stage
dynamic programming problem. We find that couples are more discriminating when forming marital unions than when forming cohabiting
unions. Cohabitation unions arise among members of the same “class” and there is overlap between the classes formed by marital
unions and cohabiting unions. This implies that some cohabiting unions progress to marriage while others do not, a finding
borne out by empirical studies.
Received: 4 November 1999/Accepted: 4 September 2000 相似文献
114.
We examine whether inflated perceptions of financial literacy affect financial decision making. Gaps between objective financial literacy and self-reported (perceived) financial literacy (blind spots) predict 19 financial behaviors better than age, gender, income, ethnicity, marital status, self-employment status, and general education levels. Only two predictors, perceived financial literacy and financial education, carried similar levels of predictive power on financial behaviors. Those with inflated perceptions of financial literacy are more likely to miss mortgage payments, receive a collection call, use informal debt, and have poor banking behavior. Those without blind spots make better financial decisions. The differences between those with and without blind spots are more pronounced among individuals with higher education and income. 相似文献
115.
Daniel J. Benjamin Matthew Rabin Collin Raymond 《Journal of the European Economic Association》2016,14(2):515-544
People believe that, even in very large samples, proportions of binary signals might depart significantly from the population mean. We model this “nonbelief in the Law of Large Numbers” by assuming that a person believes that proportions in any given sample might be determined by a rate different than the true rate. In prediction, a nonbeliever expects the distribution of signals will have fat tails. In inference, a nonbeliever remains uncertain and influenced by priors even after observing an arbitrarily large sample. We explore implications for beliefs and behavior in a variety of economic settings. 相似文献
116.
Several models for longitudinal data with nonrandom missingness are available. The selection model of Diggle and Kenward is one of these models. It has been mentioned by many authors that this model depends on untested modelling assumptions, such as the response distribution, from the observed data. So, a sensitivity analysis of the study’s conclusions for such assumptions is needed. The stochastic EM algorithm is proposed and developed to handle continuous longitudinal data with nonrandom intermittent missing values when the responses have non-normal distribution. This is a step in investigating the sensitivity of the parameter estimates to the change of the response distribution. The proposed technique is applied to real data from the International Breast Cancer Study Group. 相似文献
117.
考察物流理论演化发展的历史背景、条件和过程,可以看到20世纪80年代中期物流理论出现了由PD向Logistics的转化;20世纪90年代末至21世纪初又出现Logistics向SCM发展;随着21世纪强调知识经济和可持续发展,物流理论进一步向MF方向发展,因此,全球的物流理论呈现出“PD—k塔isticrSCM——MF”发展变化的规律和趋势。 相似文献
118.
We study experimentally the role of the network structure of pre‐play communication in determination of outcome and behavior in a multiplayer coordination game with conflicting preferences. We explore the trade‐off between the efficiency and equity of coordination outcomes and its link to the network structure of communication. Our results show substantial variations in both efficiency and equity of coordination outcomes across networks. While, as expected, increasing the length of communication improves the chance of successful coordination, it also reduces the asymmetry in the distribution of coordinated outcomes. We identify behaviors that explain variations in the distribution of coordinated outcomes both within and across networks. In all treatments, coordination is mostly explained by convergence in communication. 相似文献
119.
Yacin Jerbi 《Journal of Statistical Computation and Simulation》2013,83(3):417-433
In considering volatility as a stochastic, the aim of this paper is to estimate the four parameters related to a particular stochastic process named P1 and based on a Wiener–Levy process. We present the methodology to estimate its four parameters. We calibrate this theoretical model P1 to the CAC 40 index real data. In the same time, we test the normality of the random variables related to the two Wiener–Levy processes. The calibration is performed using the implemented aforesaid algorithm. We compare the stochastic process P1 with another process named P2 and to the Heston [Closed form solution for options with stochastic volatility with application to bonds and currency options, Rev. Financ. Stud. 6(2) (1993), pp. 327–343] process named H0 and to two other improved Heston processes named H1 and H2. For the empirical study, the same algorithm is used to calibrate the five processes. The calibration is based on a database including the CAC 40 index daily ‘closing fixing’ values for the time period from 3rd January 2005 to 22nd January 2007. The data are divided into 18 classes relative to 18 different contracts of European calls on the CAC 40 index. As a result, we find that, the normality test of the CAC 40 index is rejected which is in accordance with the previous original works dealing with this problem. For the five volatility processes, the normality test is verified almost for the same contracts. We also find that according to the used data, the process P1 and its equivalent H1 are the best for calibration. 相似文献
120.
随着物流网络这一概念的明确,对物流网络运行环境特性与对应发展模式等问题的探索已接踵而至。本文论证了物流网络应与将逐步兴起的网格环境协调发展的合理性,并展开了对物流网络与网格环境协调发展的框架结构、网络服务资源管理等一些关键问题的进一步分析。 相似文献