首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   293篇
  免费   3篇
  国内免费   2篇
管理学   40篇
民族学   1篇
人口学   2篇
丛书文集   14篇
理论方法论   44篇
综合类   104篇
社会学   30篇
统计学   63篇
  2024年   1篇
  2023年   3篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   3篇
  2020年   6篇
  2019年   11篇
  2018年   8篇
  2017年   7篇
  2016年   6篇
  2015年   2篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   30篇
  2012年   12篇
  2011年   10篇
  2010年   7篇
  2009年   11篇
  2008年   13篇
  2007年   13篇
  2006年   12篇
  2005年   17篇
  2004年   15篇
  2003年   12篇
  2002年   10篇
  2001年   10篇
  2000年   8篇
  1999年   9篇
  1998年   7篇
  1997年   8篇
  1996年   5篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   4篇
  1992年   5篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   2篇
  1986年   1篇
  1984年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1977年   1篇
排序方式: 共有298条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
51.
The team orienteering problem is an important variant of the vehicle routing problem. In this paper, a new algorithm, called Pareto mimic algorithm, is proposed to deal with it. This algorithm maintains a population of incumbent solutions which are updated using Pareto dominance. It uses a new operator, called mimic operator, to generate a new solution by imitating an incumbent solution. Furthermore, to improve the quality of a solution, it employs an operator, called swallow operator which attempts to swallow (or insert) an infeasible node and then repair the resulting infeasible solution. A comparative study supports the effectiveness of the proposed algorithm, especially, our algorithm can quickly find new better results for several large-scale instances. We also demonstrate that Pareto mimic algorithm can be generalized to solve other routing problems, e.g., the capacitated vehicle routing problem.  相似文献   
52.
We derive the asymptotic sampling distribution of various estimators frequently used to order distributions in terms of poverty, welfare, and inequality. This includes estimators of most of the poverty indices currently in use, as well as estimators of the curves used to infer stochastic dominance of any order. These curves can be used to determine whether poverty, inequality, or social welfare is greater in one distribution than in another for general classes of indices and for ranges of possible poverty lines. We also derive the sampling distribution of the maximal poverty lines up to which we may confidently assert that poverty is greater in one distribution than in another. The sampling distribution of convenient dual estimators for the measurement of poverty is also established. The statistical results are established for deterministic or stochastic poverty lines as well as for paired or independent samples of incomes. Our results are briefly illustrated using data for four countries drawn from the Luxembourg Income Study data bases.  相似文献   
53.
Quality has become a major business strategy such that organizations with successful improvement of their products quality can gain productivity, enhance market penetration, achieve great profitability, and strongly sustain their competitive advantages. The quality of materials received from suppliers determines not only the quality of assembled products but also satisfaction and loyalty of downstream customers. In this article, we employ decision-making processes of the stochastic dominance on the basis of loss-based capability indices to compare certain potential suppliers. In view of compared results of the first-order and second-order stochastic dominances, each supplier is categorized as a superior supplier, weakly superior supplier, strongly non dominated supplier, or non dominated supplier. We develop a general computational procedure to select the preferable suppliers in an analytical way. To assist decision-makers in selecting preferable suppliers, quantile-quantile plots of loss-based capability indices presenting the results of the first-order stochastic dominance of the indices’ estimators are developed so that they can simultaneously visualize pair-wise comparisons of the suppliers and make appropriate decisions. Finally, a practical example invoking the stochastic dominance using the loss-based capability indices to carry out the quality-based supplier evaluation and selection is presented to demonstrate the applicability of our proposed methodology.  相似文献   
54.
55.
用价值来衡量比较优势的利益存在货币幻觉等不足,应该用产量来衡量比较优势的好处。但是,采用aX/aY&;gt;bX/bY方法来定义的比较优势掩盖了比较优势陷阱。为深入研究比较优势和比较优势陷阱的关系,运用规范方法,采用aX/aY&;gt;1&;gt;bX/bY来重新定义比较优势,创造性地提出“比较优势边界——1”的概念。研究认为,根据比较优势陷阱系数,可以将比较优势陷阱分为“深比较优势陷阱”和“浅比较优势陷阱”,当比较优势陷阱系数等于1时,称为比较优势陷阱边界。同时,也可以运用45度对角线原则即比较优势陷阱边界——1来判定某国所处的比较优势陷阱路径,根据该路径可以分析其所实行的国际贸易政策的原因。  相似文献   
56.
睾丸酮水平(Testosterone level, T水平)是一种反映个体心理行为活动差异的新变量.T水平与认知活动、配偶选择、社会优势以及风险决策等问题的研究显示T水平是一个信度与效度较好的测量指数.T水平的变化受到社会背景在内的一些因素调节.进化理论可以整合与分析T水平相关的研究成果.T水平研究需要注意一些问题,如不同方法与不同的时间点的T水平有波动,解决这些问题可以通过引入元分析等方法.未来的研究可以深入探讨性嫉妒、行为决策等领域与T水平的关系.  相似文献   
57.
Head canting, a lateral shift of the head toward the shoulder axis, was examined in 1498 figures in the complete works of 11 painters from the XIV to the XX century: Martini, van Eyck Hubert and Jan, Holbein, Carracci, Velazquez, Rembrandt, Degas, Cèzanne, Klimt, and Modigliani. All figures (up to 9 in any one painting) that were not in complete profile and that were not depicted bowing or shifting their bodies were selected for analysis. Our analysis found a higher frequency (49%) of head canting in paintings than previously reported in naturalistic settings. Head canting was significantly higher in female figures than male figures. If a figure's head was facing laterally, head canting was more likely to be to the contralateral side. Head canting was lower in older figures than in children, youths, and adults. The highest level of head canting was seen in religious and mythological figures. Head canting was lower in figures of artists and professionals and virtually absent in depictions of nobles. Figures in pose were depicted with less head canting than those in natural settings. Head canting was lower in figures gazing toward the observer. Single-figure portraits head canted less than subjects in multiple-figure paintings. Author analysis revealed that head canting was pronounced in painters of religious subjects and in modern painters, whereas its degree was reduced in official portrait painters. These results are discussed in terms of dominance theory.  相似文献   
58.
Dr. Yellman proposes to define frequency as “a time‐rate of events of a specified type over a particular time interval.” We review why no definition of frequency, including this one, can satisfy both of two conditions: (1) the definition should agree with the ordinary meaning of frequency, such as that less frequent events are less likely to occur than more frequent events, over any particular time interval for which the frequencies of both are defined; and (2) the definition should be applicable not only to exponentially distributed times between (or until) events, but also to some nonexponential (e.g., uniformly distributed) times. We make the simple point that no definition can satisfy (1) and (2) by showing that any definition that determines which of any two uniformly distributed times has the higher “frequency” (or that determines that they have the same “frequency,” if neither is higher) must assign a higher frequency number to the distribution with the lower probability of occurrence over some time intervals. Dr. Yellman's proposed phrase, “time‐rate of events … over a particular time interval” is profoundly ambiguous in such cases, as the instantaneous failure rates vary over an infinitely wide range (e.g., from one to infinity), making it unclear which value is denoted by the phrase “time‐rate of events.”  相似文献   
59.
This paper introduces stochastic dominance as a technique to reduce the set of possible actions that a decision maker must consider in a decision problem under risk. The procedure usually does not choose an optimal action, but instead eliminates certain actions as unacceptable. Very little need be known about the decision maker's utility function. Two possible applications are presented: upgrading buildings to better withstand an earthquake; and choosing a site for a LNG facility.  相似文献   
60.
Changes in affiliative organization of 15 age-graded toddler and preschool play groups were examined in terms of assessed similarity in patterns of playmate association. Measures of peer association were derived from direct observation of social interaction during free play. The degree of between subject similarity in association profiles was derived using complete linkage hierarchical clustering procedures. Findings revealed distinct social subgroups in all social groups. Secondary analyses showed a linear increase in the size of affiliative subgroups as a function of age. Measures of interactive reciprocity within social subgroups suggested progressive consolidation of affiliative structures with age. Among older children, membership within affiliative subgroups was associated with more frequent preferences for subgroup members. Findings are discussed in terms of how children's insertion within the affiliative network of their peer group constrain socialization of their behavior and provide specific experiences that serve as contexts for the construction of more intimate interpersonal relationships.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号